您好,欢迎来到好走旅游网。
搜索
您的当前位置:首页the choice of organizational governance form and performance

the choice of organizational governance form and performance

来源:好走旅游网
JournalofManagement200329(6)937–961

TheChoiceofOrganizationalGovernanceFormandPerformance:PredictionsfromTransactionCost,Resource-based,andRealOptionsTheories

MichaelJ.Leiblein∗

FisherCollegeofBusiness,TheOhioStateUniversity,2100NeilAvenue,Columbus,OH43210-1144,USA

Received28February2003;receivedinrevisedform19May2003;accepted21May2003

Thispaperdevelopsanapproachtoorganizationalgovernancedecisionsthatrecognizeshowthechoiceoforganizationalgovernanceformaffectsboththecreationandappropriationofeconomicvalue.Thepaperbeginswithadetailedsurveyofthreetheoreticalapproaches—transactioncosteconomics(TCE),theresource-basedview(RBV),andRealOptionsanalysis(RoA)tothestudyoforganizationalgovernance.Thisreviewservestoprovidebackgroundmaterialoneachtheoryaswellastoidentifythesimilaritiesanddifferencesintheassumptionsunderlyingtheseperspectives.Aconcludingsectionprovidesaseriesofpropositionsforfutureempiricalresearchthatmayhelptointegratethesetheoriesbyincorporatingnotionsofbothvaluecreationandvalueappropriation.©2003PublishedbyElsevierInc.

Thefieldofstrategicmanagementdescribeswhyfirmsdifferintheirinvestmentchoicesandsubsequentperformance(Rumelt,Schendel&Teece,1994).Indeed,muchoftheworkinthefieldcanbecategorizedintostudiesthathaveexaminedfactorsthatinfluenceofoneelementofstrategicchoice,organizationalgovernance,andthosethathaveexaminedhowfirms’governancechoicesaffectperformance.Forexample,aprominentstrandofstrategyresearchhasexaminedtheconditionsunderwhichfirmsaremostlikelytoutilizeorganizationalgovernanceformssuchasmarketsorhierarchies(e.g.,Monteverde&Teece,1982a,1982b;Walker&Weber,1984),hierarchiesoralliances(e.g.,Pisano,1990),orequityornon-equityalliances(e.g.,Oxley,1997).Asecond,distinct,streamofresearchhasdescribedhowthedecisiontomanageaneconomicactivitythroughmarketcontracts,alliances,orhierarchyinfluencesperformanceintermsofindicatorssuchasaccounting

Tel.:+1-614-292-0071;fax:+1-614-292-7062.

E-mailaddress:leiblein1@cob.osu.edu(M.J.Leiblein).0149-2063/$–seefrontmatter©2003PublishedbyElsevierInc.doi:10.1016/S0149-2063(03)00085-0

938M.J.Leiblein/JournalofManagement200329(6)937–961

returns(D’Aveni&Ravenscraft,1994)orstockmarketreaction(McGahan&Villalonga,2003).

Whilethesetwostreamsofresearchbothinvolvethestudyofvariousorganizationalgovernanceformstheyhavelargelybeendevelopedindependentlyfromoneanother.Forinstance,muchoftheextantresearchexaminingwhyfirmschooseaparticularorgani-zationalformfollowstransactioncosteconomictheoryandarguesthattheoptimalformoforganizationisprimarilydrivenbyefficiencyconsiderations(e.g.,Williamson,1975,1985).Incontrast,priorresearchthathasexaminedtheperformanceimplicationsofspe-cificresourceinvestmentshasfrequentlyreliedonresource-basedreasoning(e.g.,Barney,1986;Rumelt,1984;Wernerfelt,1984)todescribethespecificcharacteristicsofresourcesandinvestmentsthataremostlikelytoprovidesustainablesourcesofcompetitivead-vantage.WhileworkusingRealOptionanalysishasrelatedthechoicebetweenorgani-zationalgovernanceformsandoverallfirmperformance(e.g.,Bowman&Hurry,1993;Kogut,1991),littleefforthasbeenputforthtolinkinsightsfromRealOptionanal-ysiswithinsightsfromtransactioncosteconomics(TCE)ortheresource-basedview(RBV).

Theseparationbetweenthesetheoriesoforganizationalgovernanceandcompetitiveadvantageisunfortunateforseveralreasons.First,theimportanceofcommonconceptssuchasboundedrationality,specificinvestment,anduncertaintysuggeststhatimportantconnectionsexistthatmayenhanceourunderstandingoforganizationalgovernanceanditsrelationshiptoeconomicperformance.Whiletransactionscosttheoristsarguethatspe-cificinvestmentcreatesproblemsofopportunismthatmayfrequentlyberesolvedthroughgovernancechoices(Williamson,1985),transaction-orfirm-specificinvestmentsareoftenrequiredtocreatethetypesofresourcesmostlikelytogenerateabovenormaleconomicperformance(e.g.,Mahoney,2001;McGahan,1996).Second,ifonetakesfirmsasprofitmaximizingentities,itislikelythatfirmswillchoosegovernancemechanismsthatallowthemtoassemblethenecessarybundlesofresourcesandcapturesomeoftheprofitsthataccruefromtheseresources(Riordan&Williamson,1985;Zajac&Olsen,1993).Finally,recentresearchhasdemonstratedthatthefailuretointegratetheoriesoforganizationalgovernancechoicewiththeoriesoforganizationalgovernanceformandperformancemayleadtomisleadingempiricalfindings(e.g.,Leiblein,Reuer&Dalsace,2002;Shaver,1998;Silverman,Nickerson&Freeman,1997).

Thispaperdevelopsaconceptualapproachtostudyorganizationalgovernancedecisionsthatrecognizeshowthechoiceoforganizationalgovernanceformaffectsboththecre-ationandappropriationofeconomicvalue.Thisapproachisbaseduponthreeprominenttheories—TCE,RBV,andRealOptionsanalysis(RoA).Thepaperproceedsasfollows:ThenextsectionprovidesareviewoftheTransactionCost,Resource-basedandRealOptionsliteratureasappliedtodecisionsinvolvingfirmboundaries,theacquisitionanddevelopmentofresources,andeconomicperformance.Thisreviewprovidesanexplicitstatementoftheassumptions,insights,andpropositionsthathavebeenderivedfromeachofthesetheoreti-calperspectives.Thepurposeofthisreviewistoemphasizethesimilaritiesanddifferencesintheassumptionsandpredictionsofferedbyeachtheory.Thepaperthendrawsonthiscomparisontoderiveaseriesofresearchquestionsthatarelikelytoleadtoanintegrationofthesethreeapproaches.Aconcludingsectiondiscussesopportunitiesforfutureresearchtodevelopamorerobust,integratedtheoryoforganizationalgovernance.

M.J.Leiblein/JournalofManagement200329(6)937–961939

TransactionCostEconomics

Overview

Overthelasttwentyyears,thestandardframeworkforanalyzingquestionsregardingthechoiceoforganizationalgovernanceformhasbeentransactioncosttheory(Williamson,1975,1985).Asopposedtotheneoclassicaleconomicconceptionofthefirmasaproduc-tionfunctionthatrelatesafirm’slevelofcapitalandlabortoitsproductiveoutput,TCEdescribesthefirmasanefficiency-inducingadministrativeinstrumentthatfacilitatesex-changebetweeneconomicactors.Inthisrespect,TCEfollowsHayek(1945)andBarnard(1968)inassertingthatadaptationisthecentralproblemofeconomicorganization.How-ever,incontrasttoHayek’s(1945)emphasisonthe“marvelofthemarket”whichallowsefficientcoordinationautonomouslybetweenpartiesofaneconomictransactionthroughthepricemechanismandBarnard’s(1968)emphasisonthedeeperandmorecooperativere-sponsesthatareavailablethroughconscious,deliberate,andpurposefulcoordinationwithinafirm,TCEputsforththenotionthatefficientorganizationnecessitatesmatchingtrans-actionswhichrequirehigherlevelsofcoordinationwithorganizationalgovernanceformswhichprovidethenecessarylevelsofcoordinationinacosteffectivemanner.ExcellentreviewsofthetheoryanditsapplicationareprovidedbyJoskow(1988)andBoernerandMacher(2003).

Thetwoprimaryconceptualinsightsprovidedbytransactioncosttheoryarethatthegovernanceofexchangeagreementsbetweeneconomicactorsiscostlyandthatgover-nanceformsvaryintheirabilitytofacilitateexchangedependingontheattributesinthetransactionalenvironment.Thechoiceoforganizationalgovernanceformisseenasacen-tralmeansthroughwhichmanagementaffectsthecostsofmonitoringandadministrationor,morespecifically,thecostsofnegotiatingandwritingcontractsandmonitoringandenforcingcontractualperformance(Williamson,1975).AlthoughTCEadvocatesselect-ingagovernanceformthatminimizesthesumoftotalproductionandtransactioncosts,itsapplicationhasemphasizedtheimportanceofthecostsassociatedwithgoverningandmonitoringtransactions.Duetotheeconomiesofscaleandspecializationavailableinthemarketplace,aswellastheadministrativeandincentivelimitsassociatedwithmanagingeconomictransactionswithinafirm(i.e.,hierarchicalgovernance),thetheorygenerallyassumesthatsimplemarketcontractsprovideamoreefficient,orlowercost,mechanismformanagingeconomicexchangesthanhierarchicalorganization.Giventhatmostcom-plexcontractsareincomplete,thetheoryholdsthatincertainsituationsthecostsofmarketexchangemayincreasesubstantiallyandsurpassthetechnicalefficienciesprovidedbythemarket.

PrimaryAssumptions

TherearetwomainassumptionsunderlyingtheTCEperspective.First,individualswithinafirmareassumedtobeboundedlyrationale(Cyert&March,1963;March&Simon,1958;Nelson&Winter,1982).Inspiteoftheirbesteffortstodealwiththecomplexityandunpre-dictabilityoftheworldaroundthem,theyarelimitedintheirabilitytoplanforthefutureandtoaccuratelypredictandplanforthevariouscontingenciesthatmayarise.Asaresult,

940M.J.Leiblein/JournalofManagement200329(6)937–961

itiscostly,bothintimeandresources,forindividualstoacquireandinterpretinformationaboutthecontractingenvironmentandthefirm.ThesecondassumptionunderlyingtheTCEframeworkisthatofopportunism.Theassumptionofopportunismsuggeststhatsomeeconomicactorsare“self-interestseekingwithguile”(Williamson,1975:26)orsubjectto“frailtiesofmotive”(Simon,1982:303).Althoughnotallpartiesarepronetosuchoppor-tunisticbehavior,theassumptionofboundedrationalitysuggeststhatitiscostlytoidentifyuntrustworthyindividualsexante(Williamson,1996).

Therearetwoimportantimplicationsassociatedwiththeseassumptions.First,boundedlyrationalmanagersfinditcostlytonegotiateandwritecompletecontingentclaimscontractsthatfullydescribeeachparty’sresponsibilitiesandrightsforallfuturecontingenciesthatcouldconceivablyariseduringatransaction.Thatis,marketcontractsareincomplete.Thenotionofincompletecontractssuggeststhatwhencircumstancesarisewhicharenotaccountedforintheoriginalagreement,individualswillneedtonegotiaterevisedtermswhichaddressthenewlyuncoveredcontingency.Theserenegotiationsmayleadtocalcu-latedeffortstotakeadvantageofthevulnerabilitiesofone’stradingpartnerinthehopesofachievingamorefavorabledistributionofthejointeconomicprofitsderivedfromtheexchange.Consequently,managerswillfinditvaluabletoinstitutecostlymechanismstomonitorandenforcecontractualperformancethatallowthemtoidentifynon-complianceandcommunicateinstancesofnon-compliancetoanarbiterthatmayprovideenforce-ment.

MainTheoreticalPredictions

TheprimarytheoreticalpredictionputforthbyTCEisthatof“discriminatingalignment.”Thebasicideaputforthistomatchsimpleexchangeswithsimplemodesofgovernanceandmorecomplexexchangeswithmorecomplexformsoforganization.Deviationfromtheoptimalformofgovernance,asdictatedbytransactionalattributesassociatedwithvariouscontractinghazards,ispredictedtoleadtoinefficiencies.Thus,whencontractualsafeguardsareinadequateforthehazardspresentinagivenexchange,thetheorypre-dictsthatmotivationandcoordinationcostswillrise.Typically,thesecostshavebeenassociatedwiththelikelihoodofopportunisticbehavior(Williamson,1975,1985),thepotentialforhold-up(e.g.,Klein,Crawford&Alchian,1978),challengesinmeasure-mentandmonitoring(Barzel,1982),orinsufficientlevelsofcoordination(Alchian&Demsetz,1972).Whenexcessivegovernanceisutilized,thetransactionwillbehinderedbyunnecessarilyweakincentivesandthecostsofadditionaladministration.Normativeimplicationsareoftendrawnfromsuchmodelsundertheimplicitassumptionofthepresenceofaselectionenvironmentthatensuresthatobservedgovernancechoicesareefficient.

Thenotionofdiscriminatingalignmentsuggeststhatbothtransactionsandgovernanceformsdifferinsubstantiveways.InthetheoriesofWilliamson(1975)andKleinetal.(1978),transactionsareseentodifferintermsofmarketcontractinginefficiencieswhichoriginatefromsmallnumbersbargainingsituations.Whilesmallnumbersbargainingsit-uationsmayexistexante,theprimarycontributionofTCEhascenteredonitsabilitytodescribethespecificexchangecharacteristicsthatarelikelytoleadtoexpostsmallnumberssituations.

M.J.Leiblein/JournalofManagement200329(6)937–961941

TCEmaintainsthatthelikelihoodofexpostsmallnumbersbargainingsituationsandtheresultingpotentialforopportunisticbehaviorismostlikelytooccurineconomicexchangesthatinvolvesignificantspecializedinvestment(Kleinetal.,1978;Williamson,1975,1979).Thepresenceofspecificinvestmentcreatesthreecosts.First,asthelevelofspecializedinvestmentincreases,quasi-rents(thedifferencebetweenearningsandopportunitycosts)arecreatedthatmaybesubjecttohold-up(e.g.,Kleinetal.,1978).Thepresenceofthesequasi-rentsmayresultincostlyopportunisticbargainingandhaggling.Second,inanticipa-tionofthesehold-upcosts,economicactorsmaybackwardinductandengageininefficientpositioningtactics(Grossman&Hart,1986).Forinstance,byreducingtheirlevelofspe-cificinvestment,firmsmaylimitthetotaleconomicvaluecreatedinanexchange.Finally,exchangeswhichrequireoneorbothpartiestomakesignificanttransaction-specificin-vestmentsbenefittoagreaterextentfromcoordinatedadaptation.Asaresult,thetradeoffsbetweenthehigh-poweredincentivesandautonomousadaptationofthemarketandtheaddedsafeguardsandcentralizedcoordinatingpropertiesofinternalorganizationshiftinfavorofmorefirm-likestructures.

Thetheoryindicatesthattheneedforcoordinationandthelikelihoodofopportunisticbehaviormayalsobeaffectedbythelevelofmarket,supplier,ortechnologicaluncertaintyorcomplexityinaneconomicexchange.Byincreasingthenumberofcontingenciesthatmayaffectamarketcontract,uncertaintyraisesthepotentialforopportunisticbehavioraswellastheexpectedcostsofwritingandenforcingacontingentclaimscontract(e.g.,Williamson,1985).Byinhibitingafirm’sabilitytomeasurethecontributionofanyindividualactivity,uncertaintyalsoincreasestheneedforthesuperiormonitoringandadministrativecontrolprovidedbyhierarchy(e.g.,Barzel,1982;Demsetz,1988).

Uncertaintyalsohasasecond,indirect,influenceontheexpectedcostsofexchange.Marketexchangeisnotonlyhazardousinuncertainenvironmentsbecauseitismorecostlytowritecompletecontractsintheseenvironments,butalsobecauseuncertainenvironmentsfacilitatesubsequentcontractualrenegotiationthatcanbehazardousinthepresenceofspe-cificinvestments.Sinceexchangesconductedinuncertainenvironmentsaremorelikelytoencounterunanticipatedcontingenciesthatrequirerenegotiationthanexchangesconductedinmorestableenvironments,marketfailureisparticularlylikelyinsituationswherebothhighlevelsofassetspecificityanduncertaintyarepresent.

Inmatchingtransactionscharacterizedbydifferenttypesandlevelsofexchangehazardswithappropriategovernanceforms,thetheoryindicatesthatsubstantivedifferencesexistacrossorganizationalgovernanceforms.Typically,organizationalformisconceptualizedintermsofthreedistincttypes:unilateralmarketcontracts,intermediateorhybridformsincluding“alliances,”andhierarchical,integratedfirms.Williamson(1991)maintainsthatthesedifferentgovernancestructuresvarydiscretelyintermsofincentiveintensity,admin-istrativecontrols,andcontractlawregime.Ascomparedtomarketcontracts,hierarchicalgovernanceprovidesweakerperformanceincentives.Theseweakerincentivesarethoughttopromoteateamorientation.Firmsprovideaccesstoabroaderandmoreflexiblesetofad-ministrativecontrolsystemsascomparedtomarketcontracts(Holmstrom,1979).Marketcontractsaresubjecttoclassicalcontractlawwheretheidentityofthepartiesisirrele-vantandindividualtransactionsinvolveclear“sharpin,sharpout”exchanges(Macneil,1974).Incontrast,firmsaresubjecttoanimplicitlawofforbearancewherefiatrulestheday.

942M.J.Leiblein/JournalofManagement200329(6)937–961

AssetSpecificityandOrganizationalForm

ThevastmajorityofempiricalliteratureinTCEhasexaminedthefactorswhichinflu-encethechoiceoforganizationalform.Thefollowingparagraphsbrieflysummarizethemeasurementandfindingsregardingtherelationshipbetweenassetspecificity,uncertainty,andorganizationalform.

Williamson(1996)identifiessixtypesofassetspecificity:(1)site,(2)physicalasset,(3)humanasset,(4)dedicatedasset,(5)brandnamecapital,and(6)temporal.Sitespecificityreferstotheco-locationoffacilitiessoastominimizeinventoryorproductioncosts.Ithasbeenmeasuredintermsofthephysicalproximityofcontractingparties(Joskow,1985).Physicalassetspecificityreferstotheuseofco-specializedassetsthatarecustomizedforaparticularuseorpurpose.Forinstance,theuseofspecializeddiesandequipmentassociatedwiththeuseofthosedies(Walker&Weber,1987).Humanassetspecificityreferstoanemployee’sdevelopmentoffirm-specificskillsorknowledge.Humanassetspecificityhasbeenproxiedbothbythedevelopmentofspecializedknowledgethatoc-cursasanindividualsalespersontailorshisorherworkingrelationshiptoanorganization(Anderson,1985)aswellasbythespecificityofcommunicationbetweensemiconduc-torproductdesignersandmanufacturingengineers(Monteverde,1995).Dedicatedassetspecificityreferstoadditionalinvestmentsinplantorequipmentmadeinordertoselltheincreasedoutputtoaparticularcustomer.Forexample,ithasbeenarguedthatthespecial-izeddurableassetsinJITrelationshipsrepresentaformofspecificdedicatedassets(Frazier,Spekman&O’Neal,1988).Brandnamecapitalspecificityreferstoinvestmentinreputa-tion.GatignonandAnderson(1988)arguefortheuseofadvertisingintensityasameasureofbrandnameequity.Temporalorspatialspecificityreferstoinvestmentsmadetofacilitatethetimelyresponseorcoordinationofhumanassets.Temporalspecificityhasbeenproxiedbytheuseofon-sitehumanassetsinindustriessuchasshipbuildingwherethetimingandcoordinationofconstructionsprojectsiscritical(Masten,Meehan&Snyder,1991).

Empiricalresearchhasprovidedstrongandconsistentsupportforthetheorizedrelation-shipsbetweentransaction-specificinvestmentandgovernanceform.Notablestudiesthatdemonstrateapositiverelationshipbetweenthelevelofspecificityandmoreintegratedgov-ernanceincludeMonteverdeandTeece’s(1982a,1982b)workregardingthegovernanceofautomotivecomponentsintheautomotiveassemblyindustry,Stuckey’s(1983)casestudyofthealuminumindustry,Anderson’sanalysisofthedecisiontoutilizeadirectsalesforceintheelectronicsindustry(Anderson,1985;Anderson&Schmittlein,1984),andMasten’s(1984)workintheaerospaceindustry.Morerecently,Monteverde(1995)findsthatthedecisiontointegrateproductdesignwithmanufacturingisrelatedtothelevelofrequiredinvestmentinspecifichumancapital.Inastudyfocusedonhybridgovernanceforms,Oxley(1997)findsthatmorehierarchicalalliancemodesarefavoredwhenappropriabilityhazardsarehighduetodifficultyinspecifyingorlimitingthescopeoftechnologyunderlyingthealliance.

UncertaintyandOrganizationalForm

Althoughtherelationshipbetweenuncertaintyandfirms’governancedecisionsisalsostressedinmuchoftheexistingliterature,empiricalstudieshaveyieldedfragileandat

M.J.Leiblein/JournalofManagement200329(6)937–961943

timescontradictoryresults(seeMahoney,1992;Sutcliffe&Zaheer,1998forreviews).Forinstance,empiricalstudiesfocusingononeaspectofbehavioraluncertainty—measurementuncertainty—havedemonstratedapositiverelationshipbetweentheabilitytomeasureanemployee’sproductivityandthedegreeofverticalintegration(Anderson,1985;John&Weitz,1988).Incontrast,researchfocusingontechnologicaluncertainty(e.g.,Balakrishnan&Wernerfelt,1986;Harrigan,1986;Walker&Weber,1984,1987)hasdemonstratedanegativerelationshipbetweenuncertaintyandintegration.Researchexaminingthein-fluenceofdemanduncertaintyhasillustratedbothnegative(e.g.,Harrigan,1986)andpositiverelationships(John&Weitz,1988;Levy,1985;Walker&Weber,1987)withintegration.

AsrecentlypointedoutbySutcliffeandZaheer(1998),empiricalcontradictionsre-gardingtherelationshipbetweenuncertaintyandgovernanceformmaybedue,inpart,tothedifferentsourcesofuncertaintyandvarietyofmeasuresemployed.Forinstance,be-havioralormeasurementuncertaintyhasbeenoperationalizedintermsoftheaccuracyofsalesrecords(Anderson,1985)andasthedifficultyinevaluatingperformance(Anderson&Schmittlein,1984;Poppo&Zenger,1998).Thesebehavioralmeasuresofuncertaintyhavefrequentlybeenappliedwhendiscussingthedirectrelationshipbetweenthecostofmeasuringtheoutputofapartnerandtheoptimalformoforganization.

Incontrast,theconceptofenvironmentaluncertaintyhasoftenbeenappliedtodiscussionswhichemphasizehowunforeseencontingenciesmayaffectmarketcontractsbetweentwoparties.Environmentaluncertaintyhasbeenmeasuredinperceptualtermsregardingthedegreetowhichdemand(Heide&John,1990),technology(Walker&Weber,1984),orsupplierperformance(Walker&Weber,1987)isunpredictable.ObjectivemeasuresincludeBalakrishnanandWernerfelt’s(1986)useoftheaverageageofplantandequipmentasaproxyfortechnologicaluncertainty,Levy’s(1985)useofthesumofsquarederrorsfromaregressionoftherelevantproductmarket’shistoricalunitdemandasameasureofdemanduncertainty,andHenisz’s(2000)useofpoliticalinteractiondatatoderiveameasureofpoliticaluncertainty.

Themarkethazardsthatinfluencegovernancechoicearemostlikelytooccurwhencontractrenegotiationtakesplaceinthepresenceofspecificassets.Thus,marketfailureisparticularlylikelyinsituationswherebothhighlevelsofassetspecificityanduncertaintyarepresent.Empiricalresearchhasprovidedfindingsconsistentwiththisinteractiveeffect(Coles&Hesterly,1998;Leiblein&Miller,2003;Walker&Weber,1987).

Resource-basedView

Overview

TheRBVhasemergedasanimportantexplanationforpersistentfirm-levelperformancedifferences.Incontrasttotheoriesoffirmperformancethatfocusonproduct-marketposi-tionandtheexerciseofmarketpower(e.g.,Bain,1956;Porter,1980),theRBVmaintainsthatfirmsmayenjoypersistentperformanceadvantagesduetotherelativesuperioritywithwhichtheirresourcesaddresstheneedsofcustomers.Earlycontributionsempha-sizedfirms’abilitytocreateandsustaincompetitiveadvantagebyacquiringanddefending

944M.J.Leiblein/JournalofManagement200329(6)937–961

advantageousresourcespositions.Forinstance,Wernerfelt(1984)notedthatbothproduct-andresource-marketscarcitymightleadtopersistentsourcesofadvantage.Barney(1986)describedhowimperfectionsinthemarketforstrategicfactorsmayaffectafirm’ssubse-quenteconomicperformance.LippmanandRumelt(1982)andRumelt(1984)describedhowambiguityregardingthecauseandeffectnatureoftheresourcedevelopmentprocessmightprovidesustainedsourcesofcompetitiveadvantageunderuncertainty.Thoroughre-viewsoftheresource-basedliteratureareprovidedbyMahoneyandPandian(1992)andBarneyandArikan(2001).

TheRBVprovidestwoprimaryconceptualinsights.First,itrecognizesthatfactormar-ketsexistwhereinfirmsmaydeveloporacquiretheresourcesnecessaryforproduct-marketcompetition.Second,theRBVpointsoutthattheresourceswhichleadtopersistentperformancedifferentialsaremuchbroaderinnatureandmoredifficulttoaccumulatethanthetangibleassetsandfactorsofproductiontypicallyemphasizedinneoclassicaleconomictheories.Forinstance,theresource-basedliteratureoftendrawsuponPenroses’(1959)dis-cussionoftheadministrativeandentrepreneurialskillsoftopmanagementteams,NelsonandWinter’s(1982)notionofroutines,orItami’s(1987)notionofinvisibleassetssuchastechnology,customertrust,brandimage,andcorporateculture.Giventheseinsights,theRBVdescribeshowcompetitionforresourcesmayaffectafirm’sabilitytoimplementvalu-ableproduct-marketstrategies(Wernerfelt,1984)andtocaptureeconomicvalue(Rumelt,1984).

PrimaryAssumptions

ThereareanumberofassumptionsunderlyingtheRBV.Thefirstsetofassumptionsstatethatfirmsareprofitmaximizingentitiesdirectedbyboundedlyrationalmanagers(Conner,1991;Rumelt,1984).Asaresult,managersareassumedtolacktheknowledge,foresight,andskilltoaccuratelypredictandplanforallthevariouscontingenciesthatmayariseintheirsearchforprofitableopportunities.Thesecondsetofassumptionssuggestthatfirms’mustmakeup-frontinvestmentsfortheopportunitytoengageintheprocessofcreatingnewresourceswhoseeventualvalueisinherentlyambiguousanduncertain(Lippman&Rumelt,1982).Theseassumptionsleadtothecriticalconceptsofresourceheterogeneityandresourceimmobility.Theideaofresourceheterogeneityimpliesthatcompetingfirmspossessdifferentbundlesofresources.Theideaofresourceimmobilityimpliesthatmanyoftheseresourcedifferencesmaypersistovertime.MainTheoreticalPredictions

Resource-basedlogichasusedtogeneratefourprimarypredictionsregardingcom-petitiveadvantageandperformance(Peteraf,1993).Thefirstpredictiondescribesthecharacteristicsofresourcesthatprovidetemporarysourcesofcompetitiveadvantage.Forinstance,resource-basedlogicsuggeststhatfirmsmaygaintemporarycompetitivead-vantagesbyleveragingvaluable,rare,andnon-substitutableresources.Valuableresourcesarethosethatenableformstodevelopandimplementstrategiesthathavetheeffectofincreasingcustomers’willingnesstopayorreducingasuppliers’opportunitycost(e.g.,Brandenburger&Stuart,1996).Rareresourcesarethoseforwhichdemandexceedssup-

M.J.Leiblein/JournalofManagement200329(6)937–961945

ply.Non-substitutableresourcesarethosethat,eitherinisolationorincombination,canbeuniquelyusedtohelpconceiveofandimplementastrategy.

Second,theRBVindicatesthatcompetitiveadvantagemaybesustainableifthereareexpostlimitstocompetition.Incontrasttothebarrierstocompetitionhighlightedintheindustrialorganizationliteraturesuchascapacitypreemption(Dixit,1989),spatialpre-emption(Schmalansee,1978),orcontractualpreemption(Aghion&Bolton,1978),theRBVemphasizeshowcharacteristicsintheresourcedevelopmentprocessmayinhibittheefficientimitationofcriticalresources.BarneyandArikan(2001)catalogueanumberofrationalesforresourceimmobilitythathavebeendevelopedintheRBVliterature.Forin-stance,LippmanandRumelt(1982)indicatethatthepersistenceofresourceheterogeneityacrossfirmsisduetoenforceablerightsfortheexclusiveuseofaresourceorcausalambigu-ityregardingtheapplicationofaresource.DierickxandCool(1989)suggestthatresourcesareimmobilewhentheyaresubjecttotimecompressiondiseconomies,arecausallyam-biguous,arecharacterizedbyinterconnectedassetstocks,orarecharacterizedbyassetmassefficiencies.Barney(1991)suggeststhatresourcesareinelasticinsupplywhentheyarepathdependent,causallyambiguous,orsociallycomplex.Thesenotionsofresourcehet-erogeneityandresourceimmobilityareoftenusedasstartingassumptionsforapplicationsoftheRBVframework(e.g.,Barney,1991;Wernerfelt,1984).

ThethirdpredictionofferedbytheRBVdescribestheconditionsunderwhicheconomicprofitsmaybegenerated.Inorderforafirmtoenjoyaneconomicprofitorrent,itmustgeneratemorevaluefromitsresourcesthanexpectedatthetimeoftheiracquisitionordevelopment.Thus,firmswhichacquireordevelopvaluableresourcesinfactormarketswherethereareexantelimitstocompetitionmaygeneratetemporaryeconomicprofits.Barney(1986),followingDemsetz(1973),suggeststwowaysthatmarketscanbeimper-fectlycompetitive.First,inthefaceofuncertainty,firmscanbeluckyandpurchaseordeveloparesourceatacostbelowitstrueeconomicvalue.Second,itmaybethecasethataparticularfirmhasunusualinsightsaboutthefuturevalueoftheresourcesitisacquiringordevelopinginastrategicfactormarket.Forexample,afirmmaycreateeconomicvaluethroughanacquisitionstrategythatcreatesprivatevalueaboveandbeyondthevaluebroughtbyotherbiddersandleveragesitsownvaluableandcostlytoimitateresources(Barney,1988).Similarly,afirmmaybeabletogenerateaneconomicrentinfactormarketswhereitbidsagainstfirmswhohavelessaccurateexpectationsaboutthefuturevalueofunderlyingresourcesoreconomicfactors(Makadok&Barney,2001).

ThefourthRBVpredictionsuggeststhatfirmsmaygeneratesustainedeconomicprofitsbycontinuouslyleveragingvaluable,rare,andcostlytoimitateresourcesinwaystheircompetitorscannotanticipate.Thisimpliesthatongoingeconomicprofitsaretheresultofafirmmaintainingexcesssupplyincriticalresourceswhicharebothimperfectlymo-bileandgeneralizable.Imperfectmobilityisnecessarytoinsurethattheresourceismorevaluabletothefocalfirmthananyotherpotentialbiddingfirm.Theresourcemustalsobepartiallygeneralizablesothatitcanbeextendedintonewapplications.Whiletheexistingliteratureisrelativelysilentonthecharacteristicsofresourcesthatexhibitthesetypesofcharacteristics,Rivkin(2001)developsapromisingsimulationmodelwhichsuggeststhatsuchresourcesareofmoderatecomplexity.OnemayconsiderNucor’sabilitytorepeatedlystart-upsteelmini-millproductionsites(Ghemawat,1992)orCooperIndustriesabilitytorepeatedlytransformold-linemanufacturers(Collis&Montgomery,1998)asrepresenta-

946M.J.Leiblein/JournalofManagement200329(6)937–961

tiveofmoderatelycomplexresourcesthatcompetitorshavebeenunabletoduplicateandhavebeenextendedintorelatedapplicationareas.

AlthoughtheprimarypredictionsofferedbytheRBVarewithregardtotherelationshipbetweeninvestmentinresourceswithparticularcharacteristicsandcompetitiveadvan-tageorperformance,theframeworkalsooffersdirectpredictionsregardingorganizationform.Atitsmostbasiclevel,RBVscholarshaveemphasizedhowresourceheterogene-itymayaffecttheimplicitassumptionthattransactioncostsarethedeterminingfactorineconomicorganizationbyarguingthatorganizationalformisdeterminedbyfirms’uniquestrengthsandweaknesses.Forinstance,theRBVsuggeststhattheabilitytoleveragevalu-able,firm-specificresourcesheldinexcesssupplymayleadtoamarginallyhigherlikelihoodthatfirm-hierarchywillbeoptimallychosentomanageaneconomicexchange.Thus,afirmwithauniqueandvaluableproductivecapabilitywillbemorelikelytointernalizethoseactivitiesthatarecomplementarytoitsuniquefeaturesthanfirms’thatlackthiscapability(e.g.,Argyres,1996;Barney,1999;Leiblein&Miller,2003;Quinn&Hilmer,1994).Resource-basedlogichasalsobeenusedtodescribetheconditionsunderwhichitisoptimaltocoordinatespecializedresourceswithinafirm(e.g.,Conner&Prahalad,1996;Liebeskind,1996).Thisworkfocusesalmostexclusivelyontheroleofknowledge,partic-ularlytacitknowledge,inexplainingorganizationalgovernancechoice(e.g.,Grant,1996;Kogut&Zander,1992,1993,1996;Spender,1996).Forinstance,theknowledge-basedapproachemphasizesdifficultiesassociatedwithcombiningresources(Teece,Pisano&Shuen,1997)andproposesthattheuseofafirm—asopposedtojointventures,contracts,orotherorganizationalgovernanceforms—providesasuperiormechanismforcoordinatingeconomicactivitiesrelativetootherformsoforganization.Firmsarearguedtobemoreef-ficientthanothergovernanceformssuchasmarketsatcombininganddiffusingknowledgebecauseoftheirsuperiorcoordinativeattributes(Conner,1991)andinformationprocessingabilities(Gulati&Singh,1998).Itisimportanttonotethatthisargumentisdevelopedindependentofassumptionsregardingopportunisticbehavior.Thus,evenifpartiestoanexchangearepresumedtoactingoodfaith,membersofonefirm“mayquiteliterallynotunderstandwhatanotherfirmwantsfromthem”(Langlois&Foss,1997).Thegeneralpropositionisthatfirmsexistbecausetheyarebetterthanmarketsatcreating,recombining,andtransferringcertaintypesofknowledge(e.g.,Kogut&Zander,1992).ResourcesandCompetitiveAdvantage

Thevastmajorityofempiricalliteratureintheresourced-basedtraditionhasexaminedtheperformanceimplicationsofvaluable,rare,andcostlytoimitateresources.Asthevalueofaparticularresourceiscontextspecific,thisliteraturehasdemonstratedrelationshipsbetweenawiderangeofresourcesandmeasuresofperformance.Forinstance,priorworkhasexaminedthecompetitiveimplicationsofcompetenceinfunctionalareassuchasman-ufacturing(e.g.,Pisano,1994),technologydevelopment(e.g.,Afuah,2000),andmarketing(e.g.,Schoenecker&Cooper,1998).Priorresearchhasalsoexaminedthecompetitiveim-plicationsassociatedwiththeabilitytointegrateknowledgeacrossfunctionalareas(e.g.,Henderson&Cockburn,1994)aswellastheimportanceofmaintaininganappropriatescopeofresources(e.g.,Brush&Artz,1999).Stillotherworkhasstudiedhowafirm’sresourcesaffectitsabilitytointeractwithsuppliers(e.g.,Lorenzoni&Lipparini,1999)or

M.J.Leiblein/JournalofManagement200329(6)937–961947

toengageinanalliancenetwork(e.g.,Baum&Berta,1999;McEvily&Zaheer,1999).Per-hapsthegreatestvolumeofworkhasfocusedontheimportanceofintangibleresourcessuchasreputationandculture(e.g.,Hall,1993;Rao,1994).MillerandShamsie(1996)suggestapotentiallyusefulcategorizationofresourcetypesintheirstudyoftheUSmovieindustrywheretheyproposeadistinctionbetweenproperty-andknowledge-basedresources.

Thevarietyofresourcesanalyzedinpriorstudiessuggeststheneedtomorecarefullyconsidertherelationshipbetweenspecificcategoriesofresources,product-marketposition,andcompetitiveadvantage(Priem&Butler,2001).Onerecentapproachtothisproblemhasfocusedontheconceptofresourceimmobilityatamorefine-grainedlevelbyanalyzingthebarrierstointernalandexternalknowledgetransfer(e.g.,Rivkin,2001;Szulanski,1996).AnalternativeapproachhasbeenexaminedinarecentpaperbyNickerson,HamiltonandWada(2001)whichdescribestheperformanceimplicationsof“fit”amongstrategicchoicesassociatedwithmarketposition,resourceposition,andorganizationalgovernanceform.ResourcesandOrganizationalForm

Empiricalresearchhasalsoexaminedtherelationshipbetweenthepossessionofparticu-lartypesofresourcesandorganizationalgovernanceform.Thisworkhasprovidedevidenceconsistentwiththepropositionthathighlyspecificresourcesandactivitiesaremosteffi-cientlycoordinatedwithinfirmhierarchies.Forinstance,KogutandZander(1993)havearguedthatfirmsareabletotransferknowledgethatisdifficulttounderstandandcodifyatalowercosttowhollyownedsubsidiariesthantothirdparties.Inasurveyofprojectengineers,ZanderandKogut(1995)presentresultssuggestingthatthetacitnessofmanufacturingin-novationsaffectsthedurationoftimeuntiltheycanbetransferredtothemarket.Consistentwiththisview,arecentstudybyAlmeida,SongandGrant(2002)presentsevidencefromthepatentcitationsofsemiconductorcompaniestosuggestthatmultinationalfirmsaremoreeffectiveattransferringtechnologicalknowledgeoverbothalliancesandmarkets.

RealOptionsAnalysis

Overview

RealOptionsAnalysishasemergedasacompellingapproachforevaluatinginvestmentopportunitiesinuncertainenvironments.TheconceptofrealoptionsanalysiswasproposedbyMyers(1977)whoappliedformatworkonfinancialoptionstoissuesassociatedwithcapitalbudgetingandtheallocationofR&Dresources.Notingthatsomeinvestmentoppor-tunitiesconfertheright,butnottheobligation,totakespecificoperatingactioninthefuture,thisworkemphasizedthemannerinwhichinvestmentscreateeconomicvaluethroughop-eratingflexibility.Abroadvarietyofrealoptionshavebeenstudiedinthefinanceliteratureincludingtheoptiontodeferproduction,theoptiontotemporarilyshutdownproduction,andtheoptiontochangeaproject’soutputmix(e.g.,Majd&Pindyck,1987;McDonald&Siegel,1986;Trigeorgis,1998).Inthemanagementliterature,attentionhasbeenfocusedoncorporategrowthandflexibilityoptionswithnotablestudiesexaminingaspectsofen-trepreneurialfailure(McGrath,1997),investmentinjointventures(Chi&McGuire,1996;

948M.J.Leiblein/JournalofManagement200329(6)937–961

Folta,1998;Folta&Leiblein,1994;Kogut,1991;Reuer&Leiblein,2000),marketentry(Miller&Folta,2000),andorganizationalgovernance(Leiblein&Miller,2003).Trigeorgis(1998)andCopelandandAnitkarov(2001)providerecentreviews.AdnerandLevinthal(2004)andMcGrath,Ferrier,andMendelow(2004)debatetheboundariesassociatedwiththeapplicationofrealoptionstheorytothefieldofmanagement.

TwokeyinsightsunderlietheapplicationofRealOptiontheorytothefieldofstrate-gicmanagement.First,RealOptionanalysisrecognizesthatthereareopportunitycostsassociatedwithirreversibleinvestmentunderuncertainty.Asaresult,theabilitytode-fercommittingresourcesunderuncertaintyisvaluable(e.g.,McDonald&Siegel,1986).Second,RealOptionanalysisrecognizesthatmanyinvestmentscreatevaluablefollow-oninvestmentopportunities,orgrowthoptions(Bowman&Hurry,1993;Kester,1981;Myers,1984).Takentogether,theseinsightssuggestthatcertainup-frontinvestmentsal-lowmanagementtocapitalizeonfavorableopportunitiesandmitigatenegativeshocksbyproactivelyconfrontinguncertaintyovertimeinaflexiblefashion(Kogut,1991)ratherthanbyattemptingtoavoiduncertainty(e.g.,Cyert&March,1963).Thismanagerialflexibil-itymaybeexploitedwhenthefirmreceivesnewinformationregardingmarketdemand,competitiveconditions,theviabilityofnewprocessestechnologies,andsoforth.PrimaryAssumptions

Twokeyassumptionsunderlietherealoptionperspective.First,RealOptionstheoryassumesthatmanagersareabletowritecontractsthatprovideimplicitorexplicitclaimsonfuture,follow-onopportunities.Thisassumptionimpliesthatmanagerspossessalevelofforesightsufficienttoengageinnegotiationoverthepriceandprovisionsassociatedwithacalloption,exante,thatwillmitigateexpostbargainingcostsandopportunitiesforthesellertohold-upthebuyer(e.g.,Chi&McGuire,1996).Inorderfortheholderofanoptiontocaptureeconomicvalue,shemustbeabletocreateatleastapreferentialclaimthatallowshertobenefitbyexercisingtheoptionwhenuncertaintyisresolvedfavorablyandtolimitdownsideriskbykillingtheoptionwhenuncertaintyisresolvedunfavorably.Second,RealOptionstheoryassumesthat,apriori,itispossibletospecifyadistributionofexpectedreturnsassociatedwithaninvestment.Thisassumptionimpliesthatitispossibletodevelopestimatesofthepotentialvalueassociatedwithvariousoptionstoabandon,defer,orincreaseinvestmentalongaparticularinvestmenttrajectory.ThisassumptionalsoimpliesaconceptionofuncertaintythatisclosertoKnight’s(1921)conceptofrisk,whereprobabilitiesofpotentialoutcomesareavailabletoguidechoicethanuncertainty,whereinformationistooimprecisetobeadequatelysummarizedbyprobabilities.

Therearetwoimportantimplicationsassociatedwiththeseassumptions.First,afirm’svalueconsistsoftwocomponents—thepresentvalueofexistingassetsinplaceandthepresentvaluederivedfromthecreationofdiscretionalfutureopportunities—andthevalueofthesetwocomponentsisestimable(e.g.,Miller&Modigliani,1961).Second,theRealOptionsapproachindicatesthat,foruncertainprojectsoverwhichmanagershavediscretionandcanactflexibly,traditionaltechniqueswilloftenunder-estimatevalue(Myers,1977).Theabilitytoflexiblyupdateaninvestmentplanconditionaluponthearrivalofnewinfor-mationisvaluableandthisvalueisnotaccountedforintraditionaltheoriesofinvestmentorgovernance.Thesetwoimplicationsareimportantforstudiesofcorporatedevelopment

M.J.Leiblein/JournalofManagement200329(6)937–961949

ingeneralandorganizationgovernanceinparticularbecausetheysuggestthatfirmsmaychoosegovernancestructuresinadynamicfashioninanticipationoffutureopportunities.MainTheoreticalPredictions

TheRealOptionapproachhasbeenusedtogenerateanumberofpredictionsregardingthepotentialvalueassociatedwithinvestmentsthatprovidetheoptionholderwiththeabilitytoimproveperformancebyexpandingintoattractivemarketsortechnologiesaswellastheopportunitytocontaindownsideriskbydeferringinvestment,abandoningoperations,andexpandingorcontractingactivities.Theserealoptionargumentsdescribehowfirmsmaylayclaimtofuturerentgeneratingopportunitiesthroughcurrentinvestments.ThissectiondrawsonLeibleinandMiller(2003)todescribehowoptiontheoreticprinciplesmayinfluencethemannerinwhichexchangeandfirmattributesmayinfluencechoiceoforganizationalgovernanceform.

Thefirstandsimplestmeansthroughwhichorganizationalgovernancedecisionsmaycreatevalueisthroughtheoptiontodeferinvestment.Wheninvestmentsareirreversible,thatistheycannotbefullyrecoveredwithoutincurringsomecosts,andthefuturevalueoftheseinvestmentsisuncertain,RealOptionstheoryindicatesthatcommittingprema-turelymayimposeconsiderablerisks.Inthesesituations,thereisvalueassociatedwiththeoptionofwaitingfornewinformationthatmightaffectthedesirabilityortimingoftheinvestment.Theabilitytodelayordeferanirreversibleinvestmentcanthusbeanimportantsourceofflexibility(McDonald&Siegel,1986;Pindyck,1991)andtheeco-nomicvalueassociatedwiththisflexibilitymaysuggestdeferringinvestmentevenifthestaticnetpresentvalueassociatedwiththeprojectispositive.Forinstance,ifintegrationofproductionentailsgreatersunkcoststhanproductionthroughmarketcontracting,inte-grationwillexposethefirmtotheriskofowningassetsthatmayturnouttohavelittlevalueduetochangesineithertheunderlyingtechnologyorproductdemand.Marketcon-tracting,incontrast,mayincurgreatershort-termmarginalproductioncostsbutprovidethefirmwiththeflexibilitytopursuealternativetechnologiesinthefuture.Realoptiontheoryrecognizestheexpectedvalueassociatedwiththislatterflexibilityandindicatesthat,underuncertainty,itmaybeoptimaltoutilizemarketlikemechanismsthatprovidegreaterflexibility.Thevalueassociatedwiththeoptiontodeferisgreatestwhenuncer-taintyishighandtheimmediatecashflowslostduetopostponinginvestmentarerelativelysmall.

ThesecondmeansthroughwhichRealOptionanalysisinformsorganizationalgover-nancedecisionsisthroughgrowthoptions.Growthoptionsprovidethefirmwiththeright,butnottheobligation,tolaterexpandordeveloparelatedproductortechnology.Growthoptionsareparticularlyvaluableinhigh-technologyindustrieswherethereareoftenweakappropriabilityregimesandinter-generationalknowledgespilloversaresignificant.Inthesecontexts,itwilloftenbedesirabletointernalizeactivitiesassociatedwithearlygenerationsofaproductortechnologyinordertomaintainaclaimontheopportunitytoparticipateinsubsequentgenerationsofthatproductortechnology.Forinstance,inthebiotechnologyindustry,afirmwilloftenhavetoinvestinaninternalpilotproductionprocessinordertodeveloptherequisiteexpertisenecessarytohavetheoptiontosourceorfabricateinternallyatscaleproduction.Thus,evenifitispossibletoefficientlycontractforproductioninthe

950M.J.Leiblein/JournalofManagement200329(6)937–961

marketplace,itmaybeoptimalforthefirmtointernalizethetransactioninordertomaintaintheoptionvalueassociatedwithsubsequentgenerationsoftheproduct.

Finally,theRealOptionapproachalsohelpsdescribehowfirm-levelcharacteristicsaffectdecisionsregardingorganizationalform.Afirm-levelinfluenceongovernanceissuggestedbytheRealOptiontheorypredicationthatcertainresourcescreateeconomicvaluebypro-vidingtheabilitytoflexiblyswitchuseofassets.Forinstance,KulatilakaandTrigeorgis(1994)describehowfirmsinindustrieswithvolatileproductdemandcanbenefitbyinvestinginplantandequipmentthatallowsthemtoaltertheirmanufacturedproduct-mix.However,othertypesofswitchingoptionsmayalsobecreated.Afirm’sproduct-marketdiversifica-tionstrategymayaffectitsgovernancechoicebetweeninternalandoutsourcedproductionbyalteringitsabilitytoachieveeconomiesofscaleandscopeinproduction.Forinstance,adiversifiedfirmismorelikelytoinvestinagivenprocesstechnologyknowingthatevenifdemandfortheinitialproductfailstomeetexpectation,themanufacturingfacilitymaybeconvertedforuseinoneofitsotherproductmarkets.Thus,product-marketdiversificationprovidesalowerboundontheavailablescaleafirmmayusetojustifyinternalinvestmentinagivenprocesstechnology.Similarly,andofgreaterimportanceintechnologicallyvolatilein-dustries,diversifiedfirmsareabletocontinueutilizingatechnologyafteritbecomesobsoleteinitsprimaryproduct-marketapplicationbyshiftingitsusetoaless-demandingapplication.

OpportunitiesforFutureResearch

QuestionsforDebate

ThesummariesoftheTCE,RBV,andRealOptionsliteraturesofferedintheprecedingsectionsdescribetheconditionsunderwhichitispossibletogenerateeconomicprofitsaswellashowthealignmentbetweenaneconomicexchangeandthechosenmodeofgover-nanceaffectsthedistributionofprofitsacrossfirmsinvolvedinanexchange.Asnotedinthesereviews,thethreetheoreticalstreamsdifferintheirunderlyingassumptions(seealsoSilverman,2001).Thesedifferingassumptionsofferafruitfulsetofquestionsforfurtherdebate.Opportunism

Thefirstissuefordebateisonethathasfrequentlybeenraisedintheliteratureandconcernstheassumptionofopportunism.Towhatextentisthenotionofopportunismnecessaryforatheoryoforganization?Whiletherehavebeensomecritiquesoftransactioncostsrelianceontheconceptofopportunism(Dondaldson,1990;Ghoshal&Moran,1996),resource-basedscholarshavegenerallyarguedthatopportunismissimplynotrequiredforatheoryofgovernance(Conner&Prahalad,1996).Forinstance,onereasonforhierarchicalorganizationmaybetoachieveimprovedcoordinationbetweenindependenteconomicactorsco-location.Ithasalsobeenarguedthatrelationalcontractingmayleadtoalevelof“trust”thatreducesthepropensityforopportunisticbehavior(e.g.,Ring&VandeVen,1992)andactsasasubstituteformoreformalgovernancemechanisms.Byassumingaworldofperfectrationalityandcontractingwithexplicitclaimsonfutureopportunities,therealoptionframeworkalsoleaveslittleroomforthenotionofopportunism.

M.J.Leiblein/JournalofManagement200329(6)937–961951

Insummary,theexistingliteratureoffersanumberofplausibleexplanationsregardingtheexistenceandrelativeimportanceofopportunism,coordination,andtrustindetermin-ingorganizationalgovernanceform.Whatisleftisthedifficulttaskofdevisingempiricalstudiesthatcarefullydisentangletheinfluenceofthesevariablesongovernancechoiceei-therthroughthedevelopmentofconflictinghypothesesordirectmeasurementofabstractconceptssuchasopportunismandtrust.OnepromisingavenueissuggestedbyMayerandBercovitz(2003).Inarecentstudyofcontractsintheinformationtechnologyindustry,theyproposetotestwhetherpriorrelationshipsprovidealeveloftrustthatreducestheneedformoreprotectivegovernanceprovisions(suggestingopportunismisofgreatconcern)orwhetherpriorrelationshipsprovidelearningopportunitiesthatallowtransactingorganiza-tionstoimprovetheirbilateralcoordinationthroughmorerefinedcontractualprovisions.Whiletheresultsofthisstudyvarywiththemeasurementofpriorrelationshipstrength,theirstudyisillustrativeofthetypeofstudythatmayhelptoinformthisdebate.ResourceHeterogeneity

Thesecondissuefordebate,therelativeimportanceofresourceheterogeneity,hasalsobeensubjecttomuchdiscussion.Demsetz(1988,p.147)andWinter(1988,p.175)notethatTCEsuppressesdifferencesinfirms’capabilitiesinfavorofaconcernwithincen-tives.Indeed,ithasbeenarguedthatfirms’governancechoicesarefrequentlydrivenbytheirabilitytoleverageuniquecapabilities(Bettis,Bradley&Hamel,1992;Langlois&Foss,1997;Quinn&Hilmer,1994).Therealoptionframeworksuggeststhatgovernancechoicesmayalsobeshapedbyfirms’uniqueperceptionsregardingfuturevaluegeneratingopportunities.WhileWilliamson(1998,1999)andothersrecognizethevalueassociatedwithembracingsuchresourceandstrategyheterogeneity,theyalsopointoutthesimultane-ousneedtoidentifytheconditionsunderwhichdifferentresourcesareandarenotvaluable(e.g.,Priem&Butler,2001).Assuggestedbelowinthesection“LeveragingCapabilities,”therelativeimportanceoftransactioncostsvisàviscurrentresourcesandinvestmentstakesaimedatgeneratingpotentialopportunitiesisultimatelyanempiricalquestion.RoleofUncertainty

Thethirdissuefordebateinvolvesthemeaningandimplicationofuncertainty.Inclarify-ingtheroleofuncertaintyacrosseachofthesetheoriesitmaybehelpfultorecallKnight’s(1921)distinctionbetweenriskanduncertaintywhereinriskisconsideredmeasurableintermsofstatisticalprobabilitydistributionsregardinganoutcomeortheconsequencesofanoutcome,anduncertaintyisdefinedasthelackofknowledgeregardingfuturestatesoftheworld.

ThedistinctionbetweenriskanduncertaintyprovidedbyKnightandothersprovidestwoinsights.First,thethreeapproachesdifferwithrespecttotheirrelativeemphasisonriskanduncertainty.Forinstance,whileTCEisagnosticwithregardstothedistinctionbetweenthesetwoconceptualizations,theRBVemphasizeshowuncertaintyregardingthevaluecre-atedbyjoiningtwoormoreeconomicactivitiesleadstoheterogeneous,costly-to-imitateresourceprofiles(Rumelt,1984).Inthisview,allagentshaveaccesstothesame,albeitincomplete,setofinformationandfirms’choosegovernancestructuresinaneffortto

952M.J.Leiblein/JournalofManagement200329(6)937–961

accessanddeveloppotentiallyvaluableresourcebundles.Incontrast,RealOptionstheory,atleastinitsstrictestform,emphasizestheroleofriskinitsattempttovaluetheunderly-ingdistributionoffuturereturnsandfollow-onopportunitiesassociatedwithaparticularinvestment.Second,thethreetheoriesdifferintheimportancetheyplaceonupsideanddownsideoutcomes.TCEemphasizesthedownsideassociatedwithriskoruncertaintyindescribinghowuncertaintyinthepresenceofspecificinvestmentmayleadtomisap-propriationorhold-upproblems(Williamson,1985).Incontrast,boththeRBVandRoAapproachesemphasizetheupsideprofitcreatingopportunitiesassociatedwithuncertaintyandrisk.IntheRBV,earlybetsmadeunderuncertaintyarethoughttoresultinheteroge-neousdistributionofresourceswhichprovidesustainablesourcesofadvantage.IntheRoAapproach,firmsmakeinvestmentssubjecttotheirpriorbeliefsregardingthedistributionofpotentialpayoffs.Indeed,therealoptionsviewofuncertaintymaybelinkedtoPenrose’s(1959,p.56)conceptionofuncertaintyasthelevelofanentrepreneur’sconfidenceinhisestimatesorexpectations.Theseverydifferentconceptualizationsofuncertaintysuggestaneedforadditionalresearchwhichcarefullyexaminestheinfluenceofdifferentdimensionsofuncertaintyonbothopportunismandcurrent/futurerentcreation.DirectionsforIntegration

Asempiricalresearchexistswhichindependentlysupportseachoftheseperspectives,futureadvancesarelikelytorequireacoherentandsystematicprogramthatrigorouslytestspotentialsourcesofintegrationbetweenthesetheoriesoforganizationalformandperfor-mance.LangloisandFoss(1997)proposethatjointapplicationofthetransactioncostandresource-basedapproachesmayprovideamorecomprehensiveanalysisoforganizations.Williamson(1998,1999)suggeststhatadditionalinsightislikelytobegainedbyimprov-ingourunderstandinghowfirmcompetenciesandtransactionalcharacteristicsjointlyandinteractivelydeterminetheoptimalformofeconomicorganization.Barney(1999)offersaseriesofrichexamplesthathelptoclarifythedriversofthecostofopportunisminthemar-ketandthecostofcreatingaresourcewithinthefirm.Morerecently,workhasattemptedtodevelopandtestmodelsthatlinkandintegrateconceptsfromtheseperspectives(e.g.,Argyres&Liebeskind,1999;Kogut&Kulatilaka,2001;Leiblein&Miller,2003;Jacobides&Winter,workingpaper)

Thepurposeofthissectionistoraiseaseriesofspecificquestionsthathighlightoppor-tunitiesforfutureresearchtoempiricallylinktheTCE,RBV,andRealOptionsapproachestoorganization.Inderivingquestionsthatpointtopotentiallinkages,itisinterestingtonotethatmanagersfacetwointerrelatedproblemswhendetermininganoptimalmodeofeconomicorganization.First,theymustidentifyandassembleabundleofresourcesthatcreatesvalue.Second,theymustdecidehowtocapturevaluethroughthegovernanceofthisbundleofresources.WhereastheRBVandRealOptionsapproachesprovideinsightintotheformerquestion,TCEcanprovideinsightintothelatter(e.g.,Chi,1994).Pathdependenceandinterdependence.Atabasiclevel,theRBVandRealOptionsliteraturessuggeststhatTCEdominatedviewsoforganizationmaybeextendedbychangingthelevelofanalysis,bothintermsoftimeandthetransaction.Thevalueofextendingexistingtransaction-levelanalysistoincludetheeffectsoftemporalandtransactionaldependence

M.J.Leiblein/JournalofManagement200329(6)937–961953

hasbeenacknowledgedbyWilliamson.Forinstance,Williamson(1998,p.43)describeshowafirm’shistoricalpre-commitmentsmaycreatealevelofinertiathatlocksitintoanexistingorganizationalform.Asaresult,existinggovernancealternativeswilloftenbepreferredtonewalternatives.TheroleoftemporalpathdependencealsosuggestsaconnectionbetweenTCEandtheRealOptionsliterature.TCEoftenassumesthatthemostimportantinvestmentsinexchangerelationshipsarespecificand“inflexible”innature.Asaresult,theseinvestmentsmaynotbemodifiedovertimebasedonthefirm’sexperience.Incontrast,theRealOptionsliteraturesuggeststhatastutemanagerswillpurposefullyaltertheirinvestmentprofilesinresponsetopositiveandnegativeshockstotheenvironment.Thus,forinstance,afirmutilizinganoptionsapproachmaybeexpectedtoexerciseanoptionbyshiftingamoderateformoforganizationalsuchasajointventureoralliancetoamorehierarchicalformofgovernanceinresponsetothereceiptofpositiveinformation.Thelongandextensiveliteratureoninertiaattheorganizationallevel(e.g.,Hannan&Freeman,1977,1984)suggestsanumberofwaysinwhichthissimplelogicregardingtheinfluenceofhistoryongovernancechoicemaybeextended.

Afirm’sgovernancechoicesmayalsobeinfluencedbyafirm’sportfolioofcontem-poraneousexchangerelationships.ArgyresandLiebeskind(1999)introducethenotionofgovernanceinseparabilitytodescribesituationswherethereareinterdependenciesbetweenrelatedgovernancedecisions.Intheirmodel,theformalandinformalcommitmentsem-beddedinafirm’sexistingportfolioofcontractualrelationshipsaltertheincentivestructureofsubsequentmakeorbuydecisions.Thus,afirm’spastandcurrentgovernancedecisionsconstraintherangeandtypesofgovernancemechanismsthatitcanadoptinsubsequentexchanges.Totheextentthatresourcesmightfruitfullybeoperationalizedas“clusters”oftransactions,approachesthatconsidermultipletransactionsthroughsomeformofinterde-pendencemayfacilitatetheintegrationofTCEandRBV(Williamson,1999).

Leveragingcapabilities.TheRBVandRealOptionsapproachesmayalsobeusedtoidentifyabroadersetofresourcesandinvestmentopportunitiesthatdirectlyinfluencegov-ernancedecisionsinconjunctionwithexistingtransaction-levelconcerns.Forinstance,Barney(1999)andTeece(1980,1982)describesituationswhereafirm’sgovernancedeci-sionmaybeinfluencedbyitsdesiretoexploitadvantagesintheirexpectedcostofdevelop-ingoracquiringcapabilities.TheseadditionalconsiderationssuggestthevalueinextendingexistingTCE-basedmodelsororganizationalchoicetoincludeadditionalparametersthatcapturethepotentialinfluenceofafirm’suniquecapabilitiesorfollow-onopportunitiesmayhaveoncontemporaneousgovernancechoices.Whiletherelativevarianceexplainedbycapabilityandtransaction-leveltheoriesofgovernancechoiceremainsanempiricalis-sue,itisimportanttopointoutthatextensionsofthistypedonotalterthelogicunderlyingeithertheory.Instead,bringingthetheoriestogetherinthisfashionmerelypointstoanadditional“shiftparameter”(Oxley,1999;Williamson,1991)orcomplementarylinkagebetweentheapproaches.

Empiricalresearchisemergingwhichdemonstratestherelativepredictivepowerasso-ciatedwithvariablesintendedtomeasuretransaction-,resource-,andoption-basedeffects.Argyres’s(1996)casestudyofverticalintegrationdecisionsdescribeshowfirm-specificproductioncapabilitiesandtransactioncostconcernsjointlyaffectgovernancedecisions.Silverman(1999)indicatesthatwhilefirmsaremorelikelytodiversifyintoindustrieswhere

954M.J.Leiblein/JournalofManagement200329(6)937–961

theirtechnologicalresourcebaseisvalued,theabsenceofmarkethazardsreducesthelike-lihoodofentrythroughfirmgovernanceandsuggeststhattherearecircumstancesinwhichfirmsexploittheirtechnologicalresourcesthroughcontractualmeans.LeibleinandMiller’s(2003)studyofverticalintegrationdecisionsthroughtransactioncost,resource-based,andrealoptionslensesdemonstratesthejointimportanceoftransaction-specificcharacteristicsaswellasfirm-specificproductioncapabilitiesandoptionsinthesemiconductorindustry.TotheextentthattheRBVandrealoptionsperspectivespointoutwhichassetsshouldbejoinedtocreatevalueandTCEpointsouthowtheseassetsshouldbestbegoverned,ajointapproachpromisestoaidinthedevelopmentofstrategicmanagementresearch.

Hazardmitigatingcapabilities.TheRBVmayfurtherbeusedtodevelopargumentsregardingthemannerinwhichresourcesandtransactional-characteristicsinteractivelyaffectgovernancechoice.Forinstance,theRBVmaypointtoresourceswhichprovide“hazardmitigatingcapabilities”(Delios&Henisz,2000)thatallowfirmstoutilizemar-ketcontractsinthepresenceofexchangehazards.AlongtheselinesBarneyandHansen(1994)developresource-basedlogicwhichsuggeststhatfirmswithmanagementteamsthatarebetterabletoanalyzecomplexenvironmentsarebetterabletoanticipatecontractualhazardsandthereforemorelikelytoutilizemarket-likeformsofgovernancethantherelesswell-endowedcompetitors.Reuer,ZolloandSingh(2002)developalearningapproachwhichsuggeststhatpriorinteractionsaidinthecreationofcontractingskillsassociatedwiththeabilitytocraftmorecompletecontracts,betternegotiatemarket-basedexchanges,andtoimprovemonitoringandenforcementofcontractualcompliance.

Resource-basedlogicmayalsobedevelopedwhichsuggeststhatfirms’whicharebetterabletoidentifytrustworthypartnersortodevelopareputationfortrustworthinessmaymitigateconcernsregardingopportunisticbehaviorandthereforebemorelikelytoutilizemarket-likegovernanceforms.Suchtrusthasbeentiedtopersonalexperiencesbetweenindividualsthatshareaprofessionalaffiliation(e.g.,vonHippel,1988),institutionalexperi-encesthatalloworganizationsinaparticularfieldorindustrialdistricttoobservefirmsthathavepreviouslyengagedinsuccessfulpartnerships(e.g.,Saxenian,1990),aswellaspriortiesbetweenfirms(Gulati,1995;Ring&VandeVen,1992).Totheextentthattrustmiti-gatesopportunisticbehavior,partieswilltendtosubstituterelationalgovernanceforformalcontracts(Dyer&Singh,1998).AsGulati(1995,p.93)succinctlyconcludes,“Wherethereistrust,peoplemaychoosenottorelyupondetailedcontractstoensurepredictability.”Coordinatingmechanisms.Thecontentionintheknowledge-basedbranchoftheRBVthatfirmorganizationrepresentsasocialcommunityspecializinginthecreationandtransferoftacitknowledge(e.g.,Kogut&Zander,1996)pointstoanotherpossiblemeansofinte-gratingtransaction-andfirm-leveltheoriesoforganization.Specifically,thesetwostreamssuggestthatthecoordinationmechanismsassociatedwithvariousformsoforganizationmediatetherelationshipbetweenexchangecharacteristicsandgovernancechoice.

Theknowledge-basedviewindicatesthatgovernancechoiceaffectstheeasewithwhichknowledgemaybecreatedandtransferred(e.g.,Kogut&Zander,1993).However,ithasalsobeennotedthattheuseofhigh-bandwidthcommunicationchannelsandidiosyncraticcom-municationcodesaffecttheefficacyofknowledgecreationandtransfer(e.g.,Arrow,1974;Monteverde,1995;Pelikan,1969).Therichercontextualcuesandgreaterinteractionpro-

M.J.Leiblein/JournalofManagement200329(6)937–961955

videdbyhigh-bandwidthcommunicationchannelssuchasfacetofacemeetings,physicaldemonstrationsfacilitatethedevelopmentandtransferofcomplexanduncertainknowl-edgetoagreaterextentthanlow-bandwidthchannelssuchase-mail,fax,letters,orphonecallswherethereislittleemotionalcontent,redundancy,orinteractivity.Thus,exchangeswhichinvolvehighlytacitand/orcomplexknowledgearefacilitatedbythehigh-bandwidthcommunicationchannelsandidiosyncraticcommunicationcodesassociatedwithfirmor-ganization.However,thespecificnatureofthesesameknowledgetransfermechanismscreatescontractinghazardsemphasizedbyTCE.HeimanandNickerson(2002)havebeguntodeveloplogicconsistentwiththisapproach.

Organizationalformandperformance.Inanemergingbodyofresearch,scholarsarebeginningtoexaminetheperformanceimplicationsofdecisionsregardingorganizationalform.TCEpresumesthatfirmswhosetransactionsareinappropriatelyalignedwillsufferad-verseperformanceconsequencesandeventuallyfail.MuchofthisworkfollowsAnderson(1988),inexaminingtheperformanceimplicationsofthefitbetweenfirms’governancechoicesandasetofspecificattributesofthetransactionathand.Forinstance,PoppoandZenger(1998)examinedtherelationshipbetweentransactionalmisalignmentandonedimensionofperformance,customersatisfaction,andfoundthatmanagersbecomelesssatisfiedwiththecost,quality,andresponsivenessofoutsourcedactivitiesastheseac-tivitiesbecomemorespecific.Leibleinetal.(2002)examinetheeffectsoftransactionalmisalignmentonthetechnologicalperformanceoffirmsactiveintheintegratedcircuitin-dustry.Macher(Georgetown,workingpaper)andSampson(NYU,workingpaper)provideevidencethattransactionalalignmentimprovesmanufacturingandR&Dperformance,re-spectively.Inastudyutilizingthe1980deregulationofthetruckingindustry,Silvermanetal.(1997)examinedthemortalityoflargemotorcarriersintheUStruckingindustryandfoundthatcarrierswhichfailedtoaligntheircapitalstructurewiththenormativepre-scriptionsofferedbyextanttransactioncosttheoryweremorelikelytofailthansimilarcompetitorswhomaintainedalignment.Takentogether,thesestudiessuggestthatfutureresearchwouldbenefitfromtheconstructionofintegratedmodelsoffirms’strategicchoicesaswellasthedriversandperformanceimplicationsofthosechoices.Moreover,thesestud-iesprovideearlyevidenceofthepotentialforstudieswhichexaminehowfirm-specificresources,growthoptions,andgovernancechoiceinteracttoaffectfirmperformance.

Conclusion

ThispaperprovidesasurveyofTCE,resource-based,andRealOptionstheoriesofthefirm.Asillustratedinthereview,thesethreeapproachesarebasedondifferentassumptionsregardingthenatureofeconomicactorsandtheenvironmentandprovidedifferentinsightsregardingtheoptimalnatureoffirmbehavior.Eachtheoryhasundoubtedlybeenshapedbytheeconomicenvironmentinwhichitwasfirstdevelopedand,giventheirdifferentstagesofmaturity,hasbeensubjecttoadifferentdegreeofempiricalscrutiny.Nevertheless,anexplorationoftheresearchonwhichtheseperspectivesarebasedsuggestsanumberofpromisingopportunitiesforresearchthatpushesforwardthefrontiersoforganizationaleconomicsandbridgesitmoreconcretelytootherperspectiveswithinorganizationtheory.

956M.J.Leiblein/JournalofManagement200329(6)937–961

Inaddition,thepapersuggeststhreepotentialwaysinwhichfutureempiricalworkmayproductivelyexaminehowtheresourcesandinvestmentopportunitiesidentifiedbytheRBVandRealOptionsapproachesaffecttherelationshipbetweenexchangecharacteristicsandgovernancechoiceidentifiedbyTCE.

Acknowledgments

ThedevelopmentofthispaperhasbenefitedfromconversationswithSharonAlvarez,JayBarney,TailanChi,JayDial,KonstantinaKiousis,JeffMacher,DougMiller,JacksonNickerson,JeffReuer,Hyung-deokShin,andKarenWruck.IamparticularlyindebtedtoJoMeditorDanielFeldmanforsuggestionsofferedonthispaper.Iamsolelyresponsibleforanyerrorsoromissions.

References

Adner,R.,&Levinthal,D.A.2004.Whatisnotarealoption:Consideringboundariesfortheapplicationofrealoptionstobusinessstrategy.AcademyofManagementReview,29(1):inpress.

Afuah,A.2000.Howmuchdoyourcompetitors’capabilitiesmatterinthefaceoftechnologicalchange?StrategicManagementJournal,21(3):387–404.

Aghion,P.,&Bolton,P.1987.Contractsasabarriertoentry.AmericanEconomicReview,77(3):388–400.

Alchian,A.,&Demsetz,H.1972.Production,information,andeconomicorganization.AmericanEconomicReview,62(5):777–796.

Almeida,P.,Song,J.,&Grant,R.M.2002.Arefirmssuperiortoalliancesandmarkets?Anempiricaltestofcross-borderknowledgebuilding.OrganizationScience,13(2):147–162.

Anderson,E.1985.Thesalespersonasoutsideagentoremployee:Atransactioncostanalysis.MarketingScience,4:234–254.

Anderson,E.1988.StrategicimplicationsofDarwinianeconomicsforsellingefficiencyandchoiceofintegratedorindependentsalesforces.ManagementScience,34:599–618.

Anderson,E.,&Schmittlein,D.1984.Integrationofthesalesforce:Anempiricalexamination.RANDJournalofEconomics,15(3):385–396.

Argyres,N.S.1996.Evidenceontheroleoffirmcapabilitiesinverticalintegrationdecisions.StrategicManagementJournal,17:129–151.

Argyres,N.S.,&Liebeskind,J.P.1999.Contractualcommitments,bargainingpower,andgovernanceinseparability:Incorporatinghistoryintotransactioncosttheory.AcademyofManagementReview,24(1):49–63.

Arrow,K.1974.Thelimitsoforganization.NewYork:NortonPress.

Bain,J.S.1956.Barrierstonewcompetition.Cambridge:HarvardUniversityPress.

Balakrishnan,S.,&Wernerfelt,B.1986.Technicalchange,competition,andverticalintegration.StrategicManagementJournal,9:347–359.

Barnard,C.I.1968.Thefunctionsoftheexecutive.Cambridge,MA:HarvardUniversityPress.

Barney,J.B.1986.Strategicfactormarkets:Expectations,luck,andbusinessstrategy.ManagementScience,32:1231–1241.

Barney,J.B.1988.Returnstobiddingfirmsinmergersandacquisitions:Reconsideringtherelatednesshypothesis.StrategicManagementJournal,9:71–78.

Barney,J.B.1991.Firmresourcesandsustainedcompetitiveadvantage.JournalofManagement,17(1):99–120.Barney,J.B.1999.Howafirm’scapabilitiesaffectboundarydecisions.SloanManagementReview,40(3):137–145.

M.J.Leiblein/JournalofManagement200329(6)937–961957

Barney,J.B.,&Arikan,A.2001.Theresource-basedview:Originsandimplications.InM.A.Hitt,R.E.Freeman,&J.S.Harrison(Eds.),TheBlackwellhandbookofstrategicmanagement:124–188.Malden,MA:BlackwellPublishersInc.

Barney,J.B.,&Hansen,M.H.1994.Trustworthinessasasourceofcompetitiveadvantage.StrategicManagementJournal,15(8):174–190.

Barzel,Y.1982.Measurementcostandtheorganizationofmarkets.JournalofLawandEconomics,25:27–48.Baum,J.,&Berta,W.B.1999.Sources,dynamics,andspeed:Alongitudinalbehavioralsimulationofinterorganizationalandpopulation-levellearning.AdvancesinStrategicManagement,16:155–184.

Bettis,R.A.,Bradley,S.P.,&Hamel,G.1992.Outsourcingandindustrialdecline.AcademyofManagementExecutive,6:7–22.

Boerner,C.S.,&Macher,J.T.2003.Transactioncosteconomics:Anassessmentofempiricalresearchinthesocialsciences.GeorgetownUniversityworkingpaper.

Bowman,E.H.,&Hurry,D.1993.Strategythroughtheoptionslens:Anintegratedviewofresourceinvestmentsandtheincremental-choiceprocess.AcademyofManagementReview,18(4):760–783.

Brandenburger,A.,&Stuart,H.1996.Value-basedbusinessstrategy.JournalofEconomicsandManagementStrategy,5(1):5–24.

Brush,T.H.,&Artz,K.W.1999.Towardacontingentresource-basedtheory:Theimpactofinformationasymmetryonthevalueofcapabilitiesinveterinarymedicine.StrategicManagementJournal,20(3):223–250.

Chi,T.1994.Tradinginstrategicresources:Necessaryconditions,transactioncostproblems,andchoiceofexchangestructure.StrategicManagementJournal,15:271–290.

Chi,T.,&McGuire,D.J.1996.Collaborativeventuresandvalueoflearning.Integratingthetransactioncostandstrategicoptionperspectivesonthechoiceofmarketentrymodes.JournalofInternationalBusinessStudies,27(2):285–308.

Coles,J.W.,&Hesterly,W.S.1998.Theimpactoffirm-specificassetsandtheinteractionofuncertainty:Anexaminationofmakeorbuydecisionsinpublicandprivatehospitals.JournalofEconomicBehaviorandOrganization,36:383–409.

Collis,D.J.,&Montgomery,C.A.1998.Creatingcorporateadvantage.HarvardBusinessReview,76(3):70–84.Conner,K.R.1991.Ahistoricalcomparisonofresourcebasedtheoryandfiveschoolsofthoughtwithinindustrialorganizationeconomics:Dowehaveanewtheoryofthefirm?JournalofManagement,17(1):121–154.Conner,K.R.,&Prahalad,C.K.1996.Aresource-basedtheoryofthefirm:Knowledgeversusopportunism.OrganizationScience,7(5):477–501.

Copeland,T.E.,&Antikarov,V.2001.Realoptions:Apractitioner’sguide.NewYork:Texere.

Cyert,R.M.,&March,J.G.1963.Abehavioraltheoryofthefirm.EnglewoodCliffs,NJ:Prentice-Hall.

D’Aveni,R.A.,&Ravenscraft,D.J.1994.Economiesofintegrationversusbureaucracycosts:Doesverticalintegrationimproveperformance?AcademyofManagementJournal,37:1167–1206.

Delios,A.,&Henisz,W.J.2000.Japanesefirms’investmentstrategiesinemergingeconomies.AcademyofManagementJournal,43(3):305–323.

Demsetz,H.1973.Industrystructure,marketrivalry,andpublicpolicy.JournalofLawandEconomics,16:1–9.Demsetz,H.1988.Thetheoryofthefirmrevisited.JournalofLaw,Economics,andOrganization,4(1):141–162.Dierickx,I.,&Cool,K.1989.Assetstockaccumulationandsustainabilityofcompetitiveadvantage.ManagementScience,35:1504–1511.

Dixit,A.1989.Entryandexitdecisionsunderuncertainty.JournalofPoliticalEconomy,97(3):620–639.

Dondaldson,L.1990.Theetherealhand:Organizationaleconomicsandmanagementtheory.AcademyofManagementReview,15(3):369–382.

Dyer,J.,&Singh,H.1998.Therelationalview:Cooperativestrategyandsourcesofinterorganizationalcompetitiveadvantage.AcademyofManagementReview,23:660–679.

Folta,T.1998.Governanceanduncertainty:Thetradeoffbetweenadministrativecontrolandcommitment.StrategicManagementJournal,19(11):1007–1029.

Folta,T.,&Leiblein,M.1994.Technologyacquisitionandthechoiceofgovernancebyestablishedfirms:Insightsfromoptiontheoryinamultinomiallogitmodel.AcademyofManagementProceedings:27–31.

Frazier,G.,Spekman,R.,&O’Neal,C.1988.Just-in-timeexchangerelationshipsinindustrialmarkets.JournalofMarketing,52(4):52–68.

Gatignon,H.,&Anderson,E.1988.Themultinationalcorporation’sdegreeofcontroloverforeignsubsidiaries:Anempiricaltestofatransactioncostexplanation.JournalofLaw,Economics,andOrganization,4(2):305–337.

958M.J.Leiblein/JournalofManagement200329(6)937–961

Ghemawat,P.1992.Nucoratacrossroads.HarvardBusinessSchoolcase(#9-793-039).

Ghoshal,S.,&Moran,P.1996.Badforpractice:Acritiqueoftransactioncosttheory.AcademyofManagementReview,21(1):13–48.

Grant,R.M.1996.Towardaknowledge-basedtheoryofthefirm.StrategicManagementJournal,17(Winter):109–122.

Grossman,S.,&Hart,O.1986.Thecostsandbenefitsofownership:Atheoryofverticalandlateralintegration.JournalofPoliticalEconomy,94:691–719.

Gulati,R.1995.Doesfamiliaritybreedtrust?Theimplicationsofrepeatedtiesforcontractualchoiceinalliances.AcademyofManagementJournal,38:85–112.

Gulati,R.,&Singh,H.1998.Thearchitectureofcooperation:Managingcoordinationcostsandappropriationconcernsinstrategicalliances.AdministrativeScienceQuarterly,43:781–814.

Hall,R.1993.Aframeworklinkingintangibleresourcesandcapabilitiestosustainablecompetitiveadvantage.StrategicManagementJournal,14(8):607–618.

Hannan,M.T.,&Freeman,J.H.1984.Structuralinertiaandorganizationchange.AmericanSociologicalReview,49:149–164.

Harrigan,K.R.1986.Matchingverticalintegrationstrategiestocompetitiveconditions.StrategicManagementJournal,7:535–555.

Hayek,F.A.1945.Theuseofknowledgeinsociety.AmericanEconomicReview,35(4):519–531.

Heide,J.B.,&John,G.1990.Alliancesinindustrialpurchasing:Thedeterminantsofjointactioninbuyer–supplierrelationships.JournalofMarketingResearch,27(1):24–37.

Heiman,B.,&Nickerson,J.2002.Towardsreconcilingtransactioncosteconomicsandtheknowledge-basedviewofthefirm:Thecontextofinterfirmcollaborations.InternationalJournaloftheEconomicsofBusiness,9(1):97–116.

Henderson,R.,&Cockburn,I.1994.Measuringcompetence?Exploringfirmeffectsinpharmaceuticalresearch.StrategicManagementJournal,15:63–84.

Henisz,W.J.2000.Theinstitutionalenvironmentformultinationalinvestment.JournalofLaw,Economics,andOrganization,16(2):334–364.

Holmstrom,B.1979.Moralhazardandobservability.BellJournalofEconomics,10:74–91.Itami,H.1987.Mobilizinginvisibleassets.Cambridge,MA:HarvardUniversityPress.

Jacobides,M.G.,&Winter,S.G.,2003.Capabilities,TransactionCostsandEvolution:UnderstandingtheInstitutionalStructureofProduction.WhartonSchoolWorkingPaper.

John,G.,&Weitz,B.A.1988.Forwardintegrationintodistribution:Anempiricaltestoftransactioncostanalysis.JournalofLaw,Economics,andOrganization,4:337–355.

Joskow,P.1985.Verticalintegrationandlong-termcontracts:Thecaseofcoal-burningelectricgeneratingplants.JournalofLaw,Economics,andOrganization,1(1):33–80.

Joskow,P.1988.Assetspecificityandthestructureofverticalrelationships:Empiricalevidence.JournalofLaw,Economics,andOrganization,4(1):95–117.

Klein,B.,Crawford,R.,&Alchian,A.1978.Verticalintegration:Appropriablerentsandthecompetitivecontractingprocess.JournalofLawandEconomics,21:279–326.

Knight,F.H.1921.Risk,uncertaintyandprofit.Boston,MA:HoughtonMifflin.

Kogut,B.1991.Jointventuresandtheoptiontoexpandandacquire.ManagementScience,37:19–33.

Kogut,B.,&Zander,U.1992.Knowledgeofthefirm,combinativecapabilities,andthereplicationoftechnology.OrganizationScience,3:383–397.

Kogut,B.,&Zander,U.1993.Knowledgeofthefirmandtheevolutionarytheoryofthemultinationalcorporation.JournalofInternationalBusinessStudies,24(4):625–645.

Kogut,B.,&Zander,U.1996.Whatfirmsdo?Coordination,identity,andlearning.OrganizationScience,7(5):502–519.

Kulatilaka,N.,&Trigeorgis,L.1994.Thegeneralflexibilitytoswitch:Realoptionsrevisited.InternationalJournalofFinance,62:778–798.

Langlois,R.N.,&Foss,N.J.1997.Capabilitiesandgovernance:therebrithofproductioninthetheoryofeconomicorganization.DRUIDworkingpapers97-2,DRUID,CopenhagenBusinessSchool,DepartmentofIndustrialEconomicsandStrategy/AalborgUniversity,DepartmentofBusinessStudies.

Leiblein,M.J.,&Miller,D.J.2003.Anempiricalexaminationoftransaction-andfirm-levelinfluencesontheverticalboundariesofthefirm.StrategicManagementJournal,24(9):839–860.

M.J.Leiblein/JournalofManagement200329(6)937–961959

Leiblein,M.J.,Reuer,J.J.,&Dalsace,F.2002.Domakeorbuydecisionsmatter?Theinfluenceofgovernanceontechnologicalperformance.StrategicManagementJournal,23(9):817–833.

Levy,D.T.1985.Thetransactionscostapproachtoverticalintegration:Anempiricalexamination.TheReviewofEconomicsandStatistics,67:438–445.

Liebeskind,J.P.1996.Knowledge,strategy,andthetheoryofthefirm.StrategicManagementJournal,17(Winter):93–107.

Lippman,S.A.,&Rumelt,R.P.1982.Uncertainimitability:Ananalysisofinterfirmdifferencesinefficiencyundercompetition.BellJournalofEconomics,13:418–438.

Lorenzoni,G.,&Lipparini,A.1999.Theleveragingofinterfirmrelationshipsasadistinctiveorganizationalcapability:Alongitudinalstudy.StrategicManagementJournal,20(4):317–338.

Macneil,I.1974.Themanyfuturesofcontract.SouthernCaliforniaLawReview,47:688–816.

Mahoney,J.T.1992.Thechoiceoforganizationalform:Verticalfinancialownershipversusothermethodsofverticalintegration.StrategicManagementJournal,13(8):559–584.

Mahoney,J.T.2001.Aresource-basedtheoryofsustainablerents.JournalofManagement,27:651–660.

Mahoney,J.T.,&Pandian,J.R.1992.Theresource-basedviewwithintheconversationofstrategicmanagement.StrategicManagementJournal,13(5):363–380.

Majd,S.,&Pindyck,R.S.1987.Timetobuild,optionvalue,andinvestmentdecisions.JournalofFinancialEconomics,18(1):7–28.

Makadok,R.,&Barney,J.B.2001.Strategicfactormarketintelligence:Anapplicationofinformationeconomicstostrategyformulationandcompetitorintelligence.ManagementScience,47(12):1621–1638.March,J.G.,&Simon,H.A.1958.Organizations.NewYork:JohnWiley&Sons.

Masten,S.E.1984.Theorganizationofproduction:Evidencefromtheaerospaceindustry.JournalofLawandEconomics,27:403–417.

Masten,S.E.,Meehan,J.W.,&Snyder,E.A.1991.Thecostsoforganization.JournalofLaw,Economics,andOrganization,7:1–25.

Mayer,K.,&Bercovitz,J.2003.Theinfluenceofrelationships,learningandinertiaoncontractdesign:Theextentofcontingencyplanningininformationtechnologyservicescontracts.UniversityofSouthernCaliforniaworkingpaper.

McDonald,R.,&Siegel,D.1986.Thevalueofwaitingtoinvest.QuarterlyJournalofEconomics,101(4):707–727.

McEvily,B.,&Zaheer,A.1999.Bridgingties:Asourceoffirmheterogeneityincompetitivecapabilities.StrategicManagementJournal,20(12):1133–1156.

McGahan,A.M.1996.Sustainingsuperiorprofits:Customerandsupplierrelationships.HarvardBusinessSchool(note9-797-045).

McGahan,A.M.,&Villalonga,B.2003.Howmuchdoesgovernanceformmatter.BostonUniversityworkingpaper.

McGrath,R.G.1997.Arealoptionslogicforinitiatingtechnologypositioninginvestments.AcademyofManagementReview,22(4):974–996.

McGrath,R.G.,Ferrier,W.J.,&Mendelow,A.,2004.Realoptionsasenginesofchoiceandheterogeneity.AcademyofManagementReview,29(1):inpress.

Miller,K.D.,&Folta,T.B.2002.Realoptionsinequitypartnerships.StrategicManagementJournal,23(1):77–89.

Miller,D.,&Shamsie,J.1996.Theresource-basedviewofthefirmintwoenvironments:TheHollywoodfilmstudiosfrom1936to1965.AcademyofManagementJournal,39(3):519–543.

Monteverde,K.1995.Technicaldialogasanincentiveforverticalintegrationinthesemiconductorindustry.ManagementScience,41(10):1624–1638.

Monteverde,K.,&Teece,D.J.1982a.Supplierswitchingcostsandverticalintegrationintheautomobileindustry.BellJournalofEconomics,13:206–213.

Monteverde,K.,&Teece,D.J.1982b.Appropriablerentsandquasi-verticalintegration.JournalofLawandEconomics,25:321–328.

Myers,S.C.1984.Financetheoryandfinancialstrategy.Interfaces,14(1):126–138.

Nelson,R.R.,&Winter,S.G.1982.Anevolutionarytheoryofeconomicbehaviorandcapabilities.Cambridge,MA:HarvardUniversityPress.

960M.J.Leiblein/JournalofManagement200329(6)937–961

Nickerson,J.A.,Hamilton,B.H.,&Wada,T.2001.Marketposition,resourceprofile,andgovernance:LinkingPorterandWilliamsoninthecontextofinternationalcourierandsmallpackageservicesinJapan.StrategicManagementJournal,22:251–273.

Oxley,J.E.1997.Appropriabilityhazardsandgovernanceinstrategicalliances:Atransactioncostapproach.JournalofLaw,Economics,andOrganization,13:387–409.

Oxley,J.E.1999.Institutionalenvironmentandthemechanismsofgovernance:Theimpactofintellectualpropertyonthestructureofinterfirmalliances.JournalofEconomicBehaviorandOrganization,38(3):283–300.Pelikan,P.1969.Languageasalimitingfactorforcentralization.AmericanEconomicReview,59(4):625–631.Penrose,E.T.1959.Thetheoryofthegrowthofthefirm.NewYork:Wiley.

Peteraf,M.A.1993.Thecornerstonesofcompetitiveadvantage:Aresource-basedview.StrategicManagementJournal,14:179–191.

Pindyck,R.S.1991.Irreversibility,uncertainty,andinvestment.JournalofEconomicLiterature,29(3):1110–1149.

Pisano,G.P.1990.TheR&Dboundariesofthefirm:Anempiricalanalysis.AdministrativeScienceQuarterly,35:153–176.

Pisano,G.P.1994.Knowledge,integration,andthelocusoflearning:Anempiricalanalysisofprocessdevelopment.StrategicManagementJournal,15(Winter):85–101.

Poppo,L.,&Zenger,T.1998.Testingalternativetheoriesofthefirm:Transactioncost,knowledge-based,andmeasurementexplanationsformake-or-buydecisionsininformationservices.StrategicManagementJournal,19(9):853–877.

Porter,M.E.1980.Competitivestrategy.NewYork:FreePress.

Priem,R.L.,&Butler,J.E.2001.Istheresource-based‘view’ausefulperspectiveforstrategicmanagementresearch?AcademyofManagementReview,26(1):22–41.

Quinn,J.B.,&Hilmer,F.1994.Strategicoutsourcing.SloanManagementReview,(Summer):43–55.

Rao,H.1994.Thesocialconstructionofreputation—Certificationcontests,legitimation,andthesurvivaloforgani-zationsintheAmericanautomobile-industry—1895–1912.StrategicManagementJournal,15(Winter):29–44.Reuer,J.J.,&Leiblein,M.J.2000.Downsideriskimplicationsofmultinationalityandinternationaljointventures.AcademyofManagementJournal,43:203–214.

Reuer,J.J.,Zollo,M.,&Singh,H.2002.Post-formationdynamicsinstrategicalliances.StrategicManagementJournal,23:135–151.

Ring,P.S.,&VandeVen,A.1992.Structuringcooperativerelationshipsbetweenorganizations.StrategicManagementJournal,13(7):483–494.

Riordan,M.H.,&Williamson,O.E.1985.Assetspecificityandeconomicorganization.InternationalJournalofIndustrialOrganization,3:365–378.

Rivkin,J.2001.Reproducingknowledge:Replicationwithoutimitationatmoderatecomplexity.OrganizationScience,12(3):274–294.

Rumelt,R.1984.Towardastrategictheoryofthefirm.InR.Lamb(Ed.),Competitivestrategicmanagement.EnglewoodCliffs,NJ:Prentice-Hall.

Rumelt,R.P.,Schendel,D.E.,&Teece,D.J.1994.Fundamentalissuesinstrategy.InR.P.Rumelt,D.E.Schendel,&D.J.Teece(Eds.),Fundamentalissuesinstrategy:Aresearchagenda:9–47.Boston,MA:HarvardBusinessSchoolPress.

Saxenian,A.L.1990.RegionalnetworksandtheresurgenceofSiliconValley.CaliforniaManagementReview,33(1):89–113.

Schmalansee,R.1978.Entrydeterrenceintheready-to-eatbreakfastcerealindustry.TheBellJournalofEconomics,9:305–327.

Schoenecker,T.S.,&Cooper,A.C.1998.Theroleoffirmresourcesandorganizationalattributesindeterminingentrytiming:Across-industrystudy.StrategicManagementJournal,19(12):1127–1143.

Shaver,J.M.1998.Accountingforendogeneitywhenassessingstrategyperformance:DoesentrymodechoiceaffectFDIsurvival?ManagementScience,44(4):571–585.

Silverman,B.S.1999.Technologicalresourcesandthedirectionofcorporatediversification:Towardanintegrationoftheresource-basedviewandtransactioncosteconomics.ManagementScience,45(8):1109–1124.

Silverman,B.S.,2001.Organizationaleconomics.InJ.A.C.Baum(Ed.),BlackwellCompaniontoOrganizations.London:BlackwellPublishers.

M.J.Leiblein/JournalofManagement200329(6)937–961961

Silverman,B.S.,Nickerson,J.A.,&Freeman,J.1997.Profitability,transactionalalignment,andorganizationalmortalityintheU.S.truckingindustry.StrategicManagementJournal,18(Summer):31–52.

Simon,H.1982.Modelsofboundedrationality:Behavioraleconomicsandbusinessorganization.Cambridge,MA:MITPress.

Spender,J.C.1996.Makingknowledgethebasisofadynamictheoryofthefirm.StrategicManagementJournal,17(Winter):109–122.

Stuckey,J.1983.Verticalintegrationandjointventuresinthealuminumindustry.Cambridge,MA:HarvardUniversityPress.

Sutcliffe,K.M.,&Zaheer,A.1998.Uncertaintyinthetransactionenvironment:Anempiricaltest.StrategicManagementJournal,19:1–23.

Teece,D.J.1980.Economiesofscopeandthescopeoftheenterprise.JournalofEconomicBehaviorandOrganization,1:223–245.

Teece,D.J.1982.Towardsaneconomictheoryofthemultiproductfirm.JournalofEconomicBehaviorandOrganization,3:39–63.

Teece,D.J.,Pisano,G.,&Shuen,A.1997.Dynamiccapabilitiesandstrategicmanagement.StrategicManagementJournal,18(7):509–533.

Trigeorgis,L.1998.Realoptions:Managerialflexibilityinstrategyandresourceallocation.Cambridge,MA:MITPress.

vonHippel,E.1988.Sourcesofinnovation.NewYork,NY:OxfordUniversityPress.

Walker,G.,&Weber,D.1984.Atransactioncostapproachtomake-or-buydecisions.AdministrativeScienceQuarterly,29:373–391.

Walker,G.,&Weber,D.1987.Suppliercompetition,uncertaintyandmake-or-buydecisions.AcademyofManagementJournal,30:589–596.

Wernerfelt,B.1984.Aresource-basedviewofthefirm.StrategicManagementJournal,5:171–180.

Williamson,O.E.1975.Marketsandhierarchies:Analysisandantitrustimplications.NewYork,NY:FreePress.Williamson,O.E.1979.Transactioncosteconomics:Thegovernanceofcontractualrelations.JournalofLawandEconomics,22:233–261.

Williamson,O.E.1985.Theeconomicinstitutionsofcapitalism.NewYork,NY:FreePress.

Williamson,O.E.1991.Comparativeeconomicorganization:Theanalysisofdiscretestructuralalternatives.AdministrativeScienceQuarterly,36:269–296.

Williamson,O.E.1996.Themechanismsofgovernance.NewYork,NY:OxfordUniversityPress.

Williamson,O.E.1998.Transactioncosteconomics:Howitworks;whereitisgoing.DeEconomist,146:23–58.Williamson,O.E.1999.Strategyresearch:Governanceandcompetenceperspectives.StrategicManagementJournal,20:1087–1108.

Winter,S.G.1988.Oncoase,competence,andthecorporation.JournalofLaw,Economics,andOrganization,4(1):163–181.

Zajac,E.,&Olsen,C.1993.Fromtransactioncosttotransactionalvalueanalysis:Implicationsforthestudyofinter-organizationalstrategies.JournalofManagementStudies,30(1):131–146.

Zander,U.,&Kogut,B.1995.Knowledgeandthespeedofthetransferandimitationoforganizationalcapabilities:Anempiricaltest.OrganizationScience,6(1):76–92.

MichaelJ.LeibleinisanAssistantProfessorofstrategyandmanagementintheFisherCollegeofBusinessattheOhioStateUniversity.Hisresearchfocusesonthediffusionofnewtechnologiesandtheeffectivecoordinationofresourceswithinandacrossfirms.Hisprevi-ousworkhasbeenpublishedinoutletssuchastheStrategicManagementJournal,theJournalofIndustrialEconomics,theAcademyofManagementJournal,andtheFinancialTimes.

因篇幅问题不能全部显示,请点此查看更多更全内容

Copyright © 2019- haog.cn 版权所有

违法及侵权请联系:TEL:199 1889 7713 E-MAIL:2724546146@qq.com

本站由北京市万商天勤律师事务所王兴未律师提供法律服务